Tuesday, August 4, 2009

Friday, June 12, 2009

E Squared

Here is a very interesting series by PBS correlating to sustainable development, design and transportation. There is even a whole episode about Portland. Go to the 'webcasts' tab.

design-e2.com

Transportation Infrastructure Development

by Matthew Scott Allen, June 9th, 2009

Like our nomadic ancestors, modern humans still travel, but for different and less crucial reasons. People commute to work, school or wherever they perform their daily routine. As we have learned from the mistakes of urban and suburban planning in the 20th and early 21st centuries, we found that having car-centric, sprawling cities is not sustainable. However, only with the recent spike in oil prices has the general public in North America became aware that it takes many resources to travel long distances in personal automobiles. Places such as Europe, where gas has always been expensive, have taken better measures to keep cities compact and easy to navigate without a car while also having better public transportation options.

Now, with our more recent, sprawling cities, us North Americans must adapt our surroundings to better fit a lifestyle without personal cars. You can look at models of our earlier designed cities such as Manhattan to see a place where personal automobiles are the exception, and public transportation as well as walkability are more prevalent. You can also look at places like Houston or Los Angeles where priority was placed on freeways, a way to get into and out of the city as quickly as possible . Not having a car means immobility in these places. Portland is in transition between these examples.

In the post-war boom, Portland, like most other cities in the United States started this false prospect of a suburban utopia. Many businesses in the central downtown area shut down because of competition from suburban shopping malls and easier accessibility (via cars, freeways and huge parking lots). In response, many historic and well-planned areas of downtown were demolished to make way for parking lots and garages. A good example of this was the Portland Hotel, built in 1890 and torn down in 1951 to make way for a two-story parking structure. Luckily, in 1981, this blight was demolished to make way for Pioneer Courthouse Square.

This was around the beginning of a progressive era for Portland's land use policies and priorities. Urban Growth Boundaries were created in 1973. Harbor Drive was taken out to make way for Tom McCall Waterfront Park, and funds were allocated away from building more freeways and to constructing MAX light rail and expanding bus service.

Transit-oriented development thrived with the success of the MAX, which has since expanded to become the 5th most ridden light rail in the United States. This has inspired new lines as well as Portland Streetcar, which can be credited as a major enabler of the revival of the Pearl District and Northwest Portland. Many businesses found success from MAX and street car riders as the lines became leisure and shopping corridors. There is also much new, more sustainable and dense development along the MAX lines outside of downtown. Along Interstate Ave., E. Burnside and places in Washington County such as Orenco Station have seen town center-like developments with their own places to eat, shop, play and live with easy and quick access to downtown Portland as well via light rail . This type of development on transit lines can be compared to Curitiba, Brasil's model of high density corridors along arteries served by frequent public transportation service.

Curitiba relies on a different mode of public transportation, busses, which their system is much different than what Americans are used to. Their model of the Bus Rapid Transit System devotes lanes on streets to only large busses that arrive every couple of minutes. Their system makes it faster and more simple to ride the bus than to drive, which is why 85% of the city's population uses the service. The Trinary Road System in Curitiba has encouraged high density development along these corridors, to enable as many residents to have quick access to the bus system as possible. The system has also taken out traffic lanes, to make walkability easier and to discourage traffic.

Another method of discouraging traffic congestion is to use tolls. In London, newly elected Mayor Ken Livingston created a comprehensive traffic plan and enacted the 2003 Congestion Charge. Immediately after being enabled, traffic decreased by 15% and congestion decreased by 30%. Co2 decreased by 16% and other pollutants went down by between 8% and 13%. On top of reducing emissions, the Congestion Charge generates £123 million per year, which by law must fund London's public transport infrastructure. Mayor Livingston had also provided free bus service to school children, making public transportation a more realistic option when they become adults.

Many areas which have found wealth in recent decades hesitate to use methods of transportation that the poorer, sometimes war-torn generations of our grandparents had used. Cars have been considered models of freedom and wealth, so many people hesitate to give up a part of the “American dream.”

Riding bicycles is a relatively new (and old) concept in urban cities. As the cost of owning and driving a car has skyrocketed, many have taken interest in modes of transportation that are low-cost or free. Bicycles cost far less than automobiles, don't use expensive petroleum and don't need parking permits. These are good incentives for people who may not even be environmentally conscious but are budget conscious. Luckily, they are helping the environmental cause by ceasing emissions as well as improving their health.

The best way to encourage bicycle use is to improve bicycle infrastructure. Average, unexperienced bicycle riders are less likely to ride in heavy traffic on a large avenue than they are to ride in a separated bicycle path which can be perceived as safer. Restructuring streets to make cyclists safer and better recognized by drivers is essential.

Although Portland is North America's most bike-friendly city, we still have further to go. Granted the movement has been recent, Portland has excelled very rapidly and built an expansive bicycle infrastructure. Portland can look for examples in places like Amsterdam or Copenhagen for inspiration. Those cities have such a sustainable design that they are too compact to efficiently drive cars. Therefore, bicycles have been the main source of transportation for hundreds of years.

About half of commuters in both cities commute on bike, and there are more bicycles than cars on the road at any given time. In Portland the number is around 9% in central areas. In order to persuade more Americans to ride bikes we need to make doing so more “mainstream,” easy and accessible.

A good example of a city making cycling more common and mainstream is Paris. With some of the highest pollution in the E.U. coupled with €2/ litre ($10/ gal) gas, Paris decided to take some proactive measures. Vélib', the largest and most successful bike sharing program in the world was formed. On any given day there are between 50 and 100,000 riders using Vélib'. At the same time, the ridership of personal bicycles doubled. Investing money in bicycle riding eventually leads to bicycle riding investing money in the city.

The best ways to lessen our dependence on automobiles is to create incentives to create and use other forms of transport. Redistributing money away from highways and into more comprehensive public transportation, pedestrian and cycling corridors is the way we should start and continue doing in the United States, citing the success of examples that we have seen in Brasil, Holland, Denmark and Portland.

Friday, June 5, 2009

Reflection

by Matthew Scott Allen, June 4th, 2009

I have always wondered why society is so segmented, and resources are allocated so unequally, especially within our own cities. While taking International Green Building and Development it made the correlation between sustainability and diverse housing sectors clear. When we have segregated cities, areas take turns being the desirable and undesirable locations. This can be seen with modern-day gentrification. Unfortunately, wherever the undesirable area is is coupled with poverty. What some call “slums” or “ghettos” are pockets of concentrated poverty. A big reason for these concentrations of poverty are land-use laws, municipal governments and greedy developers. Currently most inner-city areas are either very wealthy or very poor and there are relatively few middle class people or families living in the central urban areas (Manhattan has the largest income disparity in North America). The families primarily live in the suburbs, on unsustainable-designed streets far from where they work, shop and go to school, thus requiring an automobile to commute.

The concept of “New Urbanism” is relatively recent, but is a backlash to years of bad land use planning. It looks back to the era before automobile dependence and cheap petroleum, where cities were designed more densely with walking in mind. This plan not only makes everyday activities more convenient but also creates a closer-knit sense or community and social cohesion. Generally when middle class families are living in the suburbs anonymously, they don't meet their neighbors, let alone meet people of different income brackets. I believe this creates segregation and intolerance. Is it coincidental that suburban dwellers are more likely to be socially and fiscally conservative?

During the 20th century we saw rapid decline of income and infrastructure in inner city areas in North America. This was due to many reasons, notably industrial pollution, freedom of the car and in-migration of poor, sometimes African-American people from the South. Tax money and investments quickly went away from funding these areas to start funding sprawling suburbs “far away from danger” and into the artificial countryside.

The early 20th century also saw the destruction of sustainable means of transportation. Companies like General Motors and Firestone Tire used their power and money to buy out streetcar lines and then demolish them, forcing residents to further rely on automobiles (their products). They only received a slap on the wrist and trivial fines.

This move also helped widen the socio-economic gap of cities, as the poor couldn't afford cars therefore couldn't live in the suburbs. As the cities continued to crumble more and more natural ecosystems and agricultural land were destroyed to make way for suburban development. This went on through the last quarter of the 20th century as the term “inner-city” grew to become a derogatory word meaning “black”, “poor” or “ghetto”.

With the 1990s and 2000s came gentrification, which revivalists the inner-city but not the people who live there, instead displacing them. As stated earlier, this is just recirculation on the (separate) socio-economic “classes”, with hardly any cohabitation.

There are good examples, as our own exclusive Pearl District has housing for seniors and people with low to no income. However, this still leaves out the largest segment of our society- middle class families. Almost all of new development in any city center is marketed towards young urban professionals, empty-nesters, elderly and low-income. It is rare to find a new condo building that isn't upscale and has more than one or two bedrooms. This makes it impossible for a family of 4 or 5 to live in the Pearl District or other downtown areas with the same situation. There are also tight regulations for the more affordable housing: must not make income over certain “poverty level” and cannot be a student.

There is a need to build neighborhoods inclusive of all income levels, even middle class. I also think that buildings should include units built for different income levels. Living in the one section 8 building in the neighborhood makes one obvious and most likely prevents certain families from even applying.

There also needs to be access to services meeting the needs of each of the income levels. In the pearl district there are mostly expensive shops, restaurants and other services without much to cater to the residents of the section 8 buildings.

In order to create a truly sustainable society, we must cohabitate in harmony, understand the needs of our neighbors and look beyond personal income and social classes. Rich neighborhood/ poor neighborhood will not sustain a community that work together to create the future vitality of a city.

Thursday, June 4, 2009

New Urbanism Meets the Existing City


By Harvey Gant, Congress for the New Urbanism

I was drawn to and attracted by the philosophy and prin-ciples of New Urbanism immediately upon hearing aboutthem five years ago. The use of the word "new" affixedto "urbanism" suggested freshness, vitality and energy.The concepts of liveability, sustainability, small-scaleneighborhood development, walkability and moreintense utilization of public transportation were appeal-ing to someone like me, who had literally spent decadesfighting suburban sprawl. The notion that the publicrealm was important to building a sense of communitymeant a lot to me, since I had been an elected officialstruggling at times to get funding for parks, sidewalksand open space. It was also important to see the conceptof connectible streets—old gridiron patterns designed tocontrol traffic without giving automobiles dominance. Icould go on and on touting the merits of New Urbanism,for all it has meant for bettering urban settlement pat-terns and controlling sprawl read more.

Monday, June 1, 2009

The Luxury City vs. the Middle Class





By Joel Kotkin
Wednesday, May 13, 2009


Ellen Moncure and Joe Wong first met in school and then fell in love while living in the same dorm at the College of William and Mary. After graduation, they got married and, in 1999, moved to Washington, D.C., where they worked amid a large community of single and childless people.

Like many in their late 20s, the couple began to seek something other than exciting careers and late-night outings with friends. “D.C. was terrific,” Moncure recalled over lunch near her office in lower Manhattan. It was an extension of college. But after a while, you want to get to a different ‘place.’”

The ‘place’ Ellen and Joe looked for was not just a physical location but something less tangible: a sense of community and a neighborhood to raise their hoped-for children. Although they considered suburban locations, as most families do, ultimately they chose the Ditmas Park neighborhood of Brooklyn, where Joe had grown up.

At first, this seemed a risky choice. While Joe was growing up in the 1980s, the neighborhood—a mixture of Victorian homes and modest apartments—had become crime-infested. The old families were moving out, and newer ones were not replacing them. Yet Joe’s Mom still lived there, and they liked the idea of having grandma around for their planned-for family.

n a city that has been losing middle-class families for generations, the resurgence of places like Ditmas Park represents a welcome change. In recent years, child-friendly restaurants and shops have started up along once-decayed Cortelyou Road. More important, some local elementary schools have shown marked improvement, with an increase in parental involvement and new facilities.

Even in hard economic times, the area has become a beacon to New York families, as well as singles seeking a community where they will put down long-term roots. “There’s an attempt in this neighborhood to break down the city feel and to see this more as a kind of a small town,” notes Ellen. “It may be in the city, but it’s a community unto itself, a place where you can stay and raise your children.”

The Decline of the Urban Middle Class
The rise of neighborhoods like Ditmas Park suggests that cities can still nurture and accommodate a middle class. Yet sadly this trend continues to fight an uphill battle against a host of forces from high taxes and regulation to poor schools, highly bifurcated labor markets, and the scourge of crime.

These problems can be seen in the migration numbers. A demographic analysis conducted by my colleagues at the Praxis Strategy Group over the past decade found that New York and other top cities—including Chicago, Los Angeles, San Francisco, and Boston—have been suffering the largest net out-migration of residents of virtually all places in the country, albeit the pattern has slowed with the recession.

It’s astonishing that, even with the many improvements over the past decade in New York, for example, more residents left its five boroughs for other locales in 2006 than in 1993, when the city was in demonstrably far worse shape. In 2006, the city had a net loss of 153,828 residents through domestic out-migration, compared to a decline of 141,047 in 1993, with every borough except Brooklyn experiencing a higher number of out-migrants in 2006.

Since the 1990s virtually all the gains made in the New York economy have accrued to the highest income earners. Overall, New York has the smallest share of middle-income families in the nation, according to a recent Brookings Institution study; its proportion of middle-income neighborhoods was smaller than any metropolitan area, except for Los Angeles.

Much the same pattern can be seen in what has become widely touted as America’s “model city,” President Obama’s adopted hometown of Chicago. The city has also experienced a rapid loss of its largely white middle class at a rate roughly 40 percent faster than the rest of the country.

Although there has been a considerable gentrification in some pockets around Lake Michigan, Chicago remains America’s most segregated big city. In contrast to the president’s well-integrated cadre of upper-class African Americans, Chicago’s black population remains among the poorest, and most isolated, of any ethnic population in America.

And like other American cities, Chicago now has a growing glut of “luxury” condos, a pattern that became evident as early as 2006 and has now, as Chicago magazine put it, “stalled” as a result of a “perfect storm” of toughened mortgage standards, overbuilding, job losses, and rising crime.

Yet there could be some good from the current crisis. Considerable drops in urban rents and residential housing prices should ease the burdens on those who struggle with extremely high prices and taxes. Younger people, including families, may now be able to consider whether a home in Brooklyn, Chicago’s Wicker Park, or Los Angeles’ Studio City might now be affordable and desirable enough to eschew the move to the suburbs.

The Cost of Being Urban

In doing scores of interviews recently for a report on New York’s middle class, my coauthor Jonathan Bowles of the Center for an Urban Future and I ran into many people who were considering moving out of the city or had friends who had recently left. This seems particularly true in the remaining middle-class enclaves in the outer boroughs.

“Almost all the friends I grew up with have moved to Mahopac or Yorktown [in the Hudson Valley],” says Jimmy Vacca, a member of the City Council who represents communities in the Northeast Bronx such as Throgs Neck and Pelham Parkway. “There’s a flight out of many middle-class people because of the schools. A couple gets married and by the time their children gets to age five, they move.”

Costs, particularly relating to child-raising, are killing the urban middle class. Urban residents generally pay higher taxes and more for utilities, insurance, trash, and sewer than those living elsewhere. Manhattan is by far the most expensive urban area in the United States, with an average of cost of living that is more than twice as much as the national average; San Francisco, another city that has seen large-scale middle-class flight ranks second. The Washington, D.C. area, Los Angeles, and Boston also suffer extremely high living costs.

These costs are most onerous on the middle class, particularly those with children. This can be seen in the rapidly declining numbers of students in most urban school districts, including such hyped success stories as Chicago, Seattle, Portland, Washington, and San Francisco. Over the past seven years, for example, Chicago’s school system, which was run by new Education Secretary Arne Duncan, has declined by 41,000 students.

America’s core cities—including the borough of Manhattan in New York—boast among the lowest percentage of children under 17 in the nation. Although Manhattan had a much discussed “baby boomlet” (the borough’s number of toddlers under the age of 4 grew 26 percent between 2000 and 2004), once children over 5 are taken into account, Manhattan’s under-age population is well under the national average. This indicates there may be a process of exhaustion—both mental and financial—as the costs of raising children drain family resources.

The real issue for the urban middle class is not having babies but being able to sustain their families as the children age and as families expand. One reason: many middle class urbanites spend tens of thousands of dollars a year in additional expenses that those in other cities as well as surrounding suburbs often avoid. For instance, since most middle-class families in big cities today need to have two working parents just to get by, child care becomes a necessity for those without grandparents or other relatives to look after young children. In places like Chicago, Washington, Boston, San Francisco, New York, or Los Angeles these costs typically run from $13,000 to $25,000 per child annually.

Later many of these same families, if they choose to stay, must then contemplate shelling out considerable sums to send their children to private schools, particularly after the elementary level. This can add from a few thousand dollars to $30,000 a year to their annual costs—and with no tax benefit.

Do Cities Need a Middle Class?

Ultimately, in good times or bad, cities have to want a middle class to have one. And politicians, if asked, will genuflect to the idea of maintaining a middle class, yet their actions—on taxes, regulations, schools, development—suggest otherwise.

Indeed, in reality most urban areas have focused on creating what New York Mayor Michael Bloomberg famously dubbed the “luxury city.” To pay for often inflated public employee costs, the luxury city can only survive off the wealthy and on other groups—empty nesters, singles and students—who demand relatively little in the way of basic services like schools and public health facilities.

City planners and urban developers favor the unattached: the “young and restless,” the “creative class,” and the so-called “yuspie”—the young urban single professional. Champions of the unattached suggest that companies and cities should capture this segment, described by one as “the dream demographic,” if they wish to inhabit the top tiers of the economic food chain.

Another key group coveted by cities are the legions of baby boomers who have already raised children. No longer cohabiting with offspring, they are expected to give up their dull family existence and rediscover the allure of a fast-paced, defiantly “youthful” lifestyle. The new retirees, suggests luxury homebuilder Robert Toll, “are more hip-hop and happening than our parents.” They are more interested in indulging “the sophistication and joy and music that comes with city dwelling, and doesn’t come with sitting in the ’burbs watching the day go by.”

A Demographic Dead End?

This whole approach has severe limitations. Despite an enormous amount of publicity about empty nesters moving back to the city, surveys conducted by the housing industry find that most aging boomers—upwards of 70 percent—are aging in place, mostly in the suburbs. The numbers moving back into the urban core remain negligible, except in the pages of urban booster publications like The New York Times.

The young singles provide a more promising demographic for cities. But even here time may be running out. This will be even more evident between 2010 and 2020, when the millennial generation hits their 30s and early 40s and enter the prime years for family formation. Surveys of the cutting edge of this group—the other large age cohort in the population—show that most prefer a single-family home and, like their parents, seem most likely to head to the suburbs.

But perhaps most troubling of all is what this means in terms of the historic role of cities as incubators of upward mobility. Back in the 1960s, Jane Jacobs could still predict that Latino immigrants to New York, mainly from Puerto Rico, would inevitably make “a fine middle class.” Yet four decades later in the Bronx, the city’s most heavily Latino county, roughly one in three households lives in poverty, the highest rate of any urban county in the nation.

On the other extreme, in Manhattan, where the rich are concentrated, the disparities between the classes have been rising steadily. In 1980 it ranked 17th among the nation’s counties for social inequality; today it ranks first, with the top fifth of wage earners earning 52 times that of the lowest fifth, a disparity roughly comparable to that of Namibia

The University of Chicago’s Terry Nichols, one of the most articulate advocates for this new urban pattern, says cities should focus not so much as being vehicles for class mobility, but as an “entertainment machine” for the privileged. For these elite residents, the lures are not economic opportunity, but rather “bicycle paths, beaches and softball fields,” and “up-to-the-date consumption opportunities in the hip restaurants, bars, shops, and boutiques abundant in restructured urban neighborhoods.”

In this formulation cities become the domicile primarily of the young, the rich (and their servants), as well as those members of the underclass who persist in hanging around. What emerges, in the end, is a city largely without children, particularly of school-age, and with a diminishing middle class. Ironically, these are places that, despite celebrating diversity, actually could end up as hip, dense versions of the most constipated suburb imaginable.

This shift will also limit the economic functions of certain elite cities. Cost pressures, for example, have already helped Houston to replace New York and Los Angeles as the nation’s energy capital; in the future, although now humbled by the collapse of Wachovia, more middle class–oriented Charlotte, as well as other cities, could continue to gain jobs in the post-bust financial sector. Charlotte real estate developer John Harris suggests the city can compete against an expensive metropolitan region not only at the top levels of management but across the board. “It’s hard to be a mass employer in San Francisco,” he notes.

Joe Gyourko, a real estate professor at the Wharton School, suggests this elite model of urbanism will spread to other favored places such as Portland, Seattle, and possibly Austin. In all these places, we may be seeing the emergence of a European-style pattern of elite urbanism in the core, with a growing concentration of low-wage workers in the least favored parts of the urban periphery.

The City of Aspiration

Even if such a model proves sustainable, it certainly means a major change for American urbanism. Unlike most urban cultures, that of the United States has been dominated not by the dictates of princes or priests, but by the efforts of ambitious entrepreneurs and migrants.

American cities have been driven by a protean, ever-shifting commercial and middle-class culture, willing to break the bonds of tradition. As the great sociologist E. Digby Baltzell noted, the population in New York and other American cities has been “heterogeneous from top to bottom.” Social mobility, Baltzell said, constituted the fundamental reality of American urbanism.

In this country, cities emerged as the principal North American bastion for those who sought to improve their lives. As historians Charles and Mary Beard noted, “All save the most wretched had aspirations.”

Such cities often were not inherently pleasant or culturally edifying. Although its wealth would propel it to one day become the world’s cultural capital, visitors from more genteel Philadelphia and Boston often regarded 19th-century New Yorkers as crass and money-oriented.

The new cities on the opportunity frontier—Chicago, Cleveland, Cincinnati—were, if anything, even more egalitarian. After two years in Cincinnati, British writer Frances Trollope deplored how “every bee in the hive is actively employed in the search for honey…neither art, science, learning, nor pleasure can seduce them from their pursuit.” Chicago, a Swedish visitor commented in 1850, was “one of the most miserable and ugly cities” of America.

Yet these places were ideal for taking advantage of new technologies from mass manufacturing to trains and the telegraph. They created dynamic societies that provided huge opportunities for vast waves of immigrants, who by 1890 accounted for as much as half of the nation’s urban dwellers.

The newcomers were joined by others from rural America, including, by the early 20th century, many African Americans. The “Great Migration” of African Americans from the rural south, noted Gunnar Myrdal in 1944, created “a fundamental redefinition of the Negro’s status in America.” Urban life had its horrors, but in the cities it became increasing difficult to restrict a person into “tight caste boundaries.” African-American migrants from the South may have been different in many ways from newcomers from Italy, Ireland, or Russia, but their fundamental aspirations were often very much the same.

The Key to a Middle-Class Comeback: The Power of Plain Vanilla

Compared to the dismal decline in the 1970s and early 1980s, urban prospects have improved, particularly in primary urban areas such as Chicago, New York, and San Francisco. Yet, if these and other cities are to sustain their momentum, they need to look beyond “the luxury city” and to the potential of less glamorous neighborhoods that can attract the middle class and people with families.

These “plain vanilla” neighborhoods include many places that managed to resist the urban decay of the 1970s and in many cases have begun to enjoy a steady resurgence. These include, for example, large swaths of Brooklyn and Queens, as well as the lovely, park-blessed sections of south and west St. Louis, or scattered Los Angeles neighborhoods in places like the San Fernando Valley.

But these communities can only grow if cities focus on those things critical to the middle class such as maintaining relatively low density work areas and shopping streets, new schools, and parks.

This would require a massive shift in urban priorities away from the current course of subsidizing developers for luxury mega-developments, new museums, or performing arts centers. To maintain and nurture a middle class, cities need to look at the essentials that have made great cities in the past and could once again do so in the future.

The New Urban Middle Class
Perhaps the other key question is what constitutes the economic base for the people who might settle and remain in cities. It’s clear that many traditional industries—heavy manufacturing, warehousing—as well as middle management white collar jobs will diminish in the future. But it is possible to imagine the rise of a new kind of urban economy built around people working in small firms, or independently in growing fields such as information, education, healthcare, and culture, or as specialists in a wide array of business services.

These are professions that continued to grow in many older cities, even as other fields declined. In San Francisco, for example, by 2006 there were an estimated 70,000 home-based businesses and a thriving culture of self-employed “Bedouins” working in post-industrial professions. These self-employed people, noted one study, were critical to helping the city withstand the ill effects of the post-2000 dotcom collapse.

Similarly, the close-in communities of the San Fernando Valley of Los Angeles are home to large contingents of entertainment industry workers, many of them self-employed. According to studies by California State University’s Dan Blake, up to 60 percent of all L.A.-area workers in this highly dispersed industry reside somewhere in this sprawling urban region made up largely of post–World War II single-family houses. Workers in media, graphic arts, and other specialized services have also been among the few groups of middle and upper-middle income earners to see rapid growth in New York’s outer boroughs.

These post–industrial age artisans—along with more traditional parts of the middle class such as civil servants, teachers, nurses, and other service workers—could provide the critical residential base for the plain vanilla urban neighborhoods’ work. Neither rich nor poor, these artisans could use the new telecommunications net to access clients who may exist in the sprawling suburban rings, throughout the United States, or overseas.

Cities of the Future

You can see this emerging reality in places like Ditmas Park, Brooklyn. Nelson Ryland, a film editor with two children who works part-time at his sprawling turn-of-the-century Flatbush house, suggests that the key to an urban revival lies not in the spectacular but in the mundane. “It’s easy to name the things that attracted us—the neighbors, the moderate density,” he says over coffee in a house close to that occupied by Ellen and Joe. “More than anything it’s the sense of the community. That’s the great thing that keeps people like us here.”

This “sense of community” will become the key currency of sustaining urban communities. Such middle-class sensibilities get short shrift by urban scholars such as Richard Florida, who argue that in the so-called “creative age” places of residence should be “leased” like cars. In his mind, single-family homes, the ideal of homeownership, should be replaced “by a new kind of housing” that embraces higher forms of density without long-term commitment to a particular residence or location.

In fact, the sustainable city of the future will depend precisely on commitment and long-term residents. It also will rest on the revival of traditional institutions that have faded in many of today’s cities. Churches—albeit often in reinvented form—help maintain and nurture such communities. Similarly, extended family networks will be critical to future successful urban areas. As Queens resident and real estate agent Judy Markowitz puts it, “In Manhattan people with kids have nannies. In Queens, we have grandparents.”

The modest and mundane ties between people that exist in such places represent the key to reviving America’s urban regions in the coming generation. It is in our urban neighborhoods—not in the glamour zones and high-end downtowns—that our country’s cities can find a new life and purpose in the 21st century.

Joel Kotkin is a presidential fellow at Chapman University and executive director of www.newgeography.com. His next book, The Next Hundred Million, deals with the American future and is scheduled to be published in February.
http://www.american.com/archive/2009/may-2009/the-luxury-city-vs-the-middle-class/

Friday, May 29, 2009

Adams calls for end to ‘cheap, ugly housing’


Declaring that Portland has too much “cheap, ugly housing,” Mayor Sam Adams urged the Legislature to pass a bill giving the city more design control for new residential developments.
BY JIM REDDEN
The Portland Tribune, Apr 11, 2009


“We have a problem in this city with ugly houses and ugly infill,” Adams told reporters Saturday morning press during a meeting with state Sen. Rod Monroe, an East Portland Democrat who introduced Senate Bill 907, which allows Portland to review designs for medium- and high-density housing projects.

Both Adams and Monroe called on Sen. Mark Hass, a Raleigh Hills Democrat, to schedule a hearing on SB 907, before April 17, the final day for first hearings on bills at the current session.

“The city ought to be able to have some review so we can get quality housing,” Monroe said.

Hass is chairman of the Senate Education and General Government Committee, where the bill has been referred. Contacted by the Portland Tribune Monday morning, Hass said he will asked Senate President Peter Courtney to refer SB 907 to the Rules Committee, which has a later deadline for first hearings.

Adams said well-designed housing helps raise surrounding property values and encourages more investment.

Under current law, the city can review design plans downtown, in historic districts and in the Gateway Urban Renewal Area. SB 907 would extended that authority to properties along MAX light-rail lines and in “town centers” designated by Metro, the regional government, for new development.

Monroe said the legislation was especially important in the low-income areas of Portland, where much of the city’s recent growth has occurred.

“Why should low-income and handicapped people have to live in slums?” asked Monroe, who said he plans to meet with Hass early next week to request a hearing for SB 907.

The press conference was held at the MAX station at East Burnside and 148th Avenue, in front of Hazelwood Station, a housing complex that Adams and Monroe cited as an example of the results the bill would help achieve.

Among other things, the complex faces Burnside, is heavily landscaped, and has its parking lot in the back, where it is hidden from view.

Adams called the complex “beautiful.”

Bill Wilson, the architect who designed the complex, said it did not cost significantly more to build that apartments that face away from the street and have visible parking lots.

“You don’t need to have rubber stamp projects that don’t fit their lots,” said Wilson, who supports SB 907. “You can have solar orientations, and safe and secure open spaces for the residents.”

Neighborhood activist Linda Robinson also supports the bill, saying that East Portland residents deserve higher quality housing.

Metro estimates that around 300,000 new housing units must be built in the metropolitan area in coming decades to accommodate the new people projected to move here. Portland has historically taken a disproportionately large percent of the new residents, and Adams does not expect that to change even if SB 907 does not pass.

Link to article

Thursday, May 28, 2009

Jersey City Mixed-Income Community is the Next Step toward Creating the City of 2050


By Erika Schnitzer, May 15, 2009

Jersey City, N.J.–Franklin Development Group and the Jersey City Redevelopment Agency (JCRA) recently broke ground on Margaret S. Herbermann Manor, a 45-unit mixed-income community located in the Heights neighborhood of Jersey City, N.J. The development is just one component of a larger, ongoing redevelopment effort.

The expected $16 million development, which is slated for completion in the spring of 2010, will be financed by a combination of New Jersey Housing & Mortgage Finance Agency’s “CHOICE” program and M & T Bank.

“CHOICE,” conceived to encourage the development of for-sale housing in Smart Growth areas throughout N.J., focuses on home ownership. “So that we can sell the condos, there are a number of subsidies from Jersey City’s Affordable Housing Trust Fund, the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development’s HOME fund and from the New Jersey Housing & Mortgage Finance Agency,” says Paul DeBellis, Sr., president of Franklin Development Group. “In addition, what makes this unique is that one of the waterfront properties had the responsibility to supply 25 affordable housing units so it put in an additional $2.5 million in subsidies.”

Herbermann Manor is the second new workforce housing project to break ground in Jersey City, with the first being the eight-unit Harriet Tubman Townhomes. Next month, the Jersey City Redevelopment Agency plans to break ground on Mary Norton Manor, which will add an additional 24 units. In total, JCRA has approximately 300 units in the pipeline.

“The hallmark of this housing is an inclusionary policy of all income groups,” says Robert Antonicello, executive director of Jersey City Redevelopment Agency. He adds that all projects are designed for at least LEED (Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design) Silver certification “so they are sustainable and affordable to own and operate. A lot of times these get built as code housing and it becomes, for a lot of low- and moderate-income families, very expensive to live [in] because it’s expensive to maintain.”

A five-story, all-brick elevator building, Herbermann Manor's green features will include tankless hot water heaters, high efficiency air conditioning and heating, low-E windows and green landscaping.

Despite the fact that the project team was able to get the development financed, Antonicello notes, “the problem with workforce housing is that federal and local funding is aimed at people making no more than 80 percent of AMI. But you need to subsidize those between 80 and 120 percent AMI.” He adds, “We continually try to develop new sources of funding to bridge that gap,” explaining that the Jersey City Redevelopment Agency’s goal is build a model for others.

Margaret S. Herbermann Manor, which will be four stories of condominiums over one level of parking, will be comprised of five low-income units, five very low-income units, five moderate-income units and 30 workforce housing units. All residences, which are two-bedroom units, will average approximately 1,100 sq. ft., and about half of the homes will be on one level and the balance will be duplex layouts.

According to DeBellis, Sr., the units at Herbermann Manor that are set aside for those with very low incomes will sell at the 45 percent AMI level, or $60,000, the low-income units will sell at 55 percent AMI, or 79,000, the moderate-income units will sell for 72 percent AMI, or $118,000 and the workforce units will sell for $279,000.

“There are two restrictions on all units,” Debellis tells MHN. “So that they are not used for investment purposes, they have to be owner-occupied, and if the owner sells within the first five years, they have to split the profit with the State of New Jersey. The shared equity keeps [the owner] in there so they are not looking to pick up a profit.”

As Antonicello points out, affordable housing is generally concentrated in particular neighborhoods. In the case of the JCRA’s plan, the developments are spread across the city. “Now we get people who understand the housing,” Antonicello tells MHN. “We get people who approach us. In the past, people didn’t want affordable housing in their neighborhood. It’s been a paradigm shift. The flip side is they are now competing with other neighborhoods for this kind of housing. There’s a large need out there for us and we are just trying to be as creative as possible.”

Antonicello also tells MHN that JCRA is “becoming evangelical” about workforce housing.” He says, “Keep in mind that Jersey City is right across the river from New York City, where the population is 8.1 million. If we don’t produce this housing, what will happen is that market-rate housing [in Jersey City] will become much more expensive. There will be a lot of pressure on the middle-class, so we are trying to address that now. We are being proactive. We are always concerned about the city in 2050. That city is the city we’re creating.”

Link to article

Wednesday, May 27, 2009

Gentrification Issues

Podcast link:
Gentrification on KunstlerCast

The KunstlerCast is a weekly audio program about the tragic comedy of suburban sprawl.

Featuring: James Howard Kunstler, author of The Geography of Nowhere, The Long Emergency and other books.

Duncan Crary, host/producer, speaks with Kunstler weekly about the failure of suburbia and the inevitable end of this living arrangement with no future.

Friday, May 22, 2009

Haves and Have-Nots: Income Inequality in America: NPR




by Uri Berliner

NPR.org, February 5, 2007 · An America where some have more money than others is nothing new. But in the past generation, the financial gap between the rich and everyone else has grown ever wider.

This week, NPR features a seven-part series that explores the human side of income inequality in the United States. We'll have stories about workers who are severed from the middle class when their manufacturing jobs disappear. We'll be speaking with people like Larry Podeswik, a wiry 52-year-old ex-Marine who lost the best-paying job of his life when the Carrier Air Conditioning company shut down its factory in Syracuse, N.Y.

We'll meet people who have succeeded beyond their wildest expectations, because their particular skills meshed perfectly with the Internet age. We'll explore the role of luck and timing — and marriage. And we'll look at what happens when middle- and working-class students attend an elite college with much-more-affluent peers.

The Very Rich… and Everyone Else

To get a sense of how the very wealthy have prospered over the past generation, consider this: The share of total income going to the top-earning 1 percent of Americans went from 8 percent in 1980 to 16 percent in 2004.

That doesn't mean that the average family is worse off than a generation ago; more people own homes, go to college, drive reliable cars and have access to sophisticated health care than ever before. But while the average family has done well, the very rich have done much, much better.

One reason: gains in the stock market. Affluent people own more stocks, and executives are often paid in stock or stock options. So when the market does well, their wealth accelerates quickly. Over the past 10 years, for example, the S&P 500, a broad proxy for the market, has increased 86 percent. At the same time, the people at the very top saw their incomes surge: In the 1970s, corporate chief executives earned 30 times as much as the average worker. Ten years ago, CEO compensation was 116 times the average. CEOs now earn close to 300 times as much as the average worker.

During the same 10-year period, American workers became among the most productive in the rich, industrialized, world. But the growth in their wages, when adjusted for inflation, was spotty at best.

What's Behind the Gap?

This widening gulf between the haves and have-nots has been a consistent trend for a generation or more. Economists largely agree about the primary underlying reasons. New technology has made many jobs obsolete, while creating dramatic opportunities for wealth in computers, finance, and media and entertainment. Global competition has done the same. As middle-class assembly-line jobs vanish, and routine white-collar work gets outsourced overseas, the value of education and special skills rises. The power of unions continues to decline.

For people in the broad middle class, the economic picture over the past decade has been mixed. Unemployment has been low and inflation largely contained. But behind those reassuring trends, you'll find a lot of volatility in labor markets — what economists call "churn." In short, there's more hiring and firing going on.

That churn had led to new opportunities for many workers, but caused hardship and anxiety for many others. Add to this the fast-rising cost of health care and the decline of employer-paid pensions, and you understand why many middle-class families describe themselves as financially squeezed. Low-income Americans, of course, are financially squeezed as well, only more so.

Is the System Broken?

Even the staunchest free-market advocates agree that a widening income gap can be harmful to a society if it cuts people off from economic opportunity. But they aren't convinced that is happening now.

Economists and others who dismiss fears about the income gap point to the low unemployment rate, rising home ownership and a fertile environment for entrepreneurship as evidence that economic opportunity is alive and well. And they argue that it's fine and well if the rich are getting a lot richer, as long as most other people make some economic progress and have the opportunity to make a lot more.

But others – including many politicians — are convinced that something has gone awry in our economic system, threatening the underpinning of the American Dream. Former Sen. John Edwards of North Carolina based his 2004 bid for the Democratic nomination for president on a "two Americas" theme. Democrat James Webb made economic insecurity a centerpiece of his Senate victory in traditionally Republican Virginia. President Bush hasn't emphasized income inequality much during his administration. But he pointedly mentioned it twice last week in a speech on Wall Street. Better schools, he said, can help close the wealth divide.

Action on Capitol Hill

Democrats in Congress have begun to introduce legislation designed to assist lower- and middle-income Americans, from raising the minimum wage to cutting interest rates on student loans. They will try to change labor laws to make it easier for unions to organize. And many will oppose an extension of the Bush administration tax cuts that have benefited wealthier Americans.

Conservatives tend to be mistrustful of any attempt to fix income inequality by making new laws. And they argue that the big increase in single-parent families has contributed significantly to the wealth gap — more so than liberals often acknowledge.

Economists of all political persuasions believe income inequality transcends partisan politics: Neither party caused it, and neither party has the means to reverse it. There are just too many forces at work for the wealth gap to be halted by a flurry of bills passed in Washington.

Article on NPR.org

Saturday, May 16, 2009

New Urbanism

New Urbanism is an urban design movement that promotes a return to traditional neighborhoods, as well as the revitalization of cities and town centers. It was officially founded in the 1990’s by a group of renegade architects and planners, in reaction to sprawling development patterns of the automobile era. The Congress for the New Urbanism (CNU) spearheads the effort to create compact, walkable neighborhoods.

New Urbanism (NU) takes many forms. It includes masterplanned communities like Traditional Neighborhood Developments (TND) and Transit Oriented Developments (TOD), but also smaller projects, such as a group of renovated row houses within an existing city block.

History of Suburbia

James Howard Kunstler, writer and critic of the American surburban landscape, explains that suburbs emerged because people wanted to flee the true horrors — pollution, bad air, poor sanitation, crime — of industrial cities of the late 19th and early 20th centuries [1]. People yearned for a cabin in the woods or a little house in the country, or at least an escape from the factories that were filling the central city.

However, before the car, some of America’s best building and urban design was being done in early decades of the 20th century. Good examples of neighborhood design are found in streetcar suburbs and in small towns, along Main Street, USA. These neighborhoods, mixed-used and scaled for people, are the standard that many New Urbanists try to emulate today.

With the rise of the automobile after World War II, Kunstler describes that suburbia "became a cartoon of itself. It became a cartoon of ‘country life.’ It was no longer country living in any meaningful way; it had become basically industrial living in an industrial box in a fake country setting.” [1] Most American suburbs, especially those built between 1970 and the present, are cheaply constructed, poorly designed and hastily planned.

History of New Urbanism

New Urbanism began to take shape after Seaside, Florida was developed in 1981. Seaside opened as an old-style, walkable neighborhood that displayed attractive architecture and thoughtful design – all of which were rare for new construction at the time. By the 1990’s, there was growing frustration with suburban sprawl, so an alternative vision would easily attract scores of devoted followers.

Congress for the New Urbanism

The Congress for the New Urbanism, formed in 1993, is the founding organization of the New Urbanism movement. It sponsors annual meetings called Congresses, where “architects, landscape architects, planners, economists, real estate agents and developers, lawyers, government officials, educators, citizen activists, and students discuss issues related to the health and vitality of regions, towns, and neighborhoods.” [2] CNU was originally assembled by Peter Katz, who became the group’s first Executive Director.

The organization takes a very broad approach and “advocates the restructuring of public policy and development practices to support the restoration of existing urban centers and towns within coherent metropolitan regions.” [2]

Charter

The Charter for the New Urbanism [3], unveiled in 1996, establishes the principles of NU that revolve around reinvesting in central cities, reconfiguring suburbs and preserving countryside – with the goal of creating real places. The charter is divided into three main sections that descend in spatial scale:

The Region: Metropolis, city, and town
The neighborhood, the district and the corridor
The block, the street and the building

Each section presents 9 principles that should be considered not only by New Urbanist planners and architects, but by all decisionmakers involved in urban development. One key idea is that cities and towns should have recognizable centers and borders, beyond which new construction is strictly avoided. In addition, neighborhoods should be “compact, pedestrian-friendly, and mixed-use”. Regional architectural styles, historic preservation and shared public space are also crucial.

Canons of Sustainable Architecture and Urbanism

CNU created an addendum to its charter – partly in response to criticism has been leveled at New Urbanism, but also to address the emerging environmental crises of the new century. For example, critics pointed out that several New Urbanist developments were built on farmland or open space, much like sprawling subdivisions. The Canons [4] attempt to link green building with urban planning, while emphasizing environmental issues like land conservation and global warming.

Hurricane Katrina

Hurricane Katrina brought New Urbanism national attention, as New Urbanist planners were called upon to help rebuild New Orleans and the Gulf Coast.

New Urbanist Developments: Some Examples

Seaside, Florida, USA (1981)

The Kentlands in Gaithersberg, Maryland, USA (1989)

Oceanview Lofts in Berkeley, California, USA (1993)

Celebration, Florida, USA (1995)

Civano in Tucson, Arizona, USA (1997)

Orenco Station in Portland, Oregon, USA (1997)

Highland Terrace, Louisville, Kentucky, USA (2000)

Paseo Colorado in Pasadena, California, USA (2000)

Del Mar Station, Pasadena, California, USA (2003)


Criticism

One of the most salient critiques of New Urban projects is that many of them have consumed valuable farmland and open space. Just like conventional suburbs, they sometimes sit far from town centers. CNU’s revised Canons have therefore called for building primarily on urban infill and urban adjacent land.

Link to article

Thursday, May 14, 2009

Economic Segregation Impacting Education

News & Notes: NPR , October 30, 2007

Listen to story

A new study released by the Southern Education Foundation shows that most public school students in the South are from low-income households.

Joining Farai Chideya to talk about the implications of that finding are Lynn Huntley, president of the Southern Education Foundation, and Joseph Edelin, a teacher at Kipp Ways Academy in Atlanta, Ga.

Link to article

Tuesday, May 12, 2009

THE STABILITY OF MIXED INCOME COMMUNITIES


by Douglas J. Krupka, January 2006

Income segregation is a visible aspect in American urban areas. Many believe that the presence of isolated populations of the poor in central cities and inner ring suburbs has important effects on residents, including reducing upward mobility. The undesirable sideeffects of economic sorting underlie policy interest in creating and sustaining mixed-income communities in American metropolitan areas. To varying degrees, federal, stateand local governments all attempt to induce greater income mixing in select neighborhoods through regulation and subsidies. While proponents of these efforts assume that if a mixed income neighborhood can be created, the income mixing that is induced will persist, the accuracy of this assertion has never been directly tested.

The level of economic segregation in American metropolitan areas offers something of a puzzle. Mixed income neighborhoods exist in all cities, despite the broad pattern of economic segregation. Standard urban economic models predict strict sorting along economic lines (Alonso 1964, Muth 1969, Tiebout 1956), a result that motivated a line of research explaining mixed-income neighborhoods. 1 Taking a cue from studies of racial sorting, the prevailing approach to explaining mixed-income neighborhoods tends to rely on the assumption that residents obtain additional enjoyment or benefits from living in such neighborhoods. Nonetheless, the results from these models are not very robust; often the mixed equilibrium is only one of several equally likely outcomes or occurs only for arelatively small range of parameter values. These studies ignore the fact that the standard models predicting economic segregation describe long-run equilibria while the income-mixing data are derived from cross-sectional snapshots of urban areas in America at a single point in time. A dynamic interpretation of models that predict income segregation implies that mixed income neighborhoods may exist due to transitional factors, but will not be stable in the long run. The fundamental question then becomes: are mixed-incomeneighborhoods self-sustaining equilibrium outcomes or are they simply observations of transient states, neighborhoods that are in the midst of changing from one income group to another? New research by Krupka (2005) offers the first rigorous attempt to empirically answer this question.

The analysis of mixed-income neighborhood stability presents subtle statistical issues. The standard models of income segregation suggest lengthy periods of transitional mixing. In the standard Alonso/Muth model, people sort by income into homogenous neighborhoods because different income groups value land differently and the marketallocates land to valued uses. However, secular trends like population in-migration or uneven growth in income across the population are likely to change the structure of an urban area slowly; neighborhoods will not instantaneously change to accommodate the new income group. Costs of relocation and housing stock adjustment slow this adjustment process down considerably. If this transitional process is at all extensive, census data simply cannot speak to the stability of mixed income neighborhoods.

Tiebout offers a model of income segregation whereby families sort into jurisdictions in order to maximize their utility derived from the consumption of public services like education, police protection and garbage pick-up. If the demand for these and other public services exhibit strong income effects, people will sort into jurisdictions based on income. However, if public service levels are slow to adjust to demographic changes in the community, it may take a considerable amount of time before indigenous residents realize that non-preferred service levels are not aberrations, but permanent deficiencies in the community. It is only as families realize this transition is irreversible that they will consider a move to a new jurisdiction. The intervening years will likely include long periods of uncertainty as the political process works out which income group “wins” and gets its preferred level of services. During these periods, jurisdictions will exhibit substantial mixing, but this is no sign that the mixing represents a stable situation.

Finally, if we adopt Schelling’s (1969) approach of assuming people have direct preferences for the incomes of their neighbors, income mixing again appears to beunsustainable at the neighborhood level. These income preferences could arise from various sources: neighborhood externalities, or demand effects on the provision of privategoods and services. This equilibrium, however, is most likely reached via a long transitional period whenever demographic or economic change in the metropolitan area as a whole cause neighborhood instability. These transition periods will exhibit large amounts of income mixing, as classes are thrown into neighborhoods together and wait to see which class will become the dominant group in the neighborhood. If these transitions are at all drawn out, cross sectional estimates of mixing will simply not reflect the long-run equilibrium level of mixing, and cannot yield any insights into long run neighborhood stability

Krupka’s (2005) empirical study of mixed-income stability draws from a private data set that compiles demographic, economic and housing information at the census block group level, and connects census geographies over thirty years. With this data it is possible to use the census block group as the unit of observation to study how neighborhoods change over time. There are three predictions that the models of income segregation make. Allof them are interpretations of the idea that income mixing is not a stable equilibrium. The first prediction is that neighborhoods that exhibit large amounts of income mixing will tend to become more homogenous over time. Second, income mixing will be a result of instability in neighborhood demographics. Finally, a mixed incomeneighborhood, because it is unstable, will tend to have larger changes in demographic mix over the ensuing time period as sorting occurs, and the neighborhood empties out except for a homogenous group

The study tests these predictions using the standard deviation of income in theneighborhood as a measure of the amount of income mixing. Demographic instability (or change) is measured by the magnitude of the change in neighborhood median income. Several control variables are included in the empirical analysis. The results suggest thatneighborhood demographic shocks are indeed a primary predictor of income mixing, while prior income mixing is a strong predictor of subsequent demographic transitions, just as the standard economic segregation models predict.

The most important result, however, is that the amount of income mixing does indeed decrease over time. All else equal, the most conservative estimates reveal that a typicalmixed neighborhood will lose at least 20 per cent of its standard deviation in incomes over ten years. This estimate ranges to as much as 70 per cent per decade in some cases.

These results are important for two reasons. First, they are consistent with the prevailingview of neighborhood income mixing as a transitional phenomenon. The branch of the economics literature which has struggled to explain mixed-income neighborhoods as stable equilibrium outcomes appears to be on the wrong track.

On the other hand, stable mixed-income communities have been a public policy goal for some time. Local housing agencies, redevelopment authorities and HUD have all offered incentives to developers to induce the development of such communities. The logic ofsuch policies would seem to be that mixed-income communities, while preferred by all,are unprofitable because of some sort of market imperfection.

In the face of these policy initiatives, it is important to understand how and why income mixing occurs. If it is the case that people prefer to live in mixed neighborhoods but real estate markets do not provide them, then the policies encouraging such development will be correcting a market failure. The empirical evidence, however, indicates that this is not the case; whatever households’ expressed attitudes about income-mixing per se, economic forces shaped by household residence decisions, business location and/or public service provision do not allow extremely mixed neighborhoods to persist.

This is not to say that public policy has no place in encouraging mixed-incomeneighborhoods. There are justifications for valuing such communities beyond households’ preferences. The fact that income mixing within block groups is so substantial (over 60 per cent of the total variance in income occurs within block-group boundaries) might give planners hope that sustaining mixed neighborhoods is not impossible. Nonetheless, this empirical research indicates that market forces work against income-mixing so that mixed-income advocates must recognize that maintaining such neighborhoods requires sustained policy over time

Link to article

Friday, May 8, 2009

Low income housing: beneficial for students?

Mat Lindenberg - The Clipper, 10/10/08

As tuition and other college expenses and the pure cost of living escalate, more and more students in Washington and across the nation are finding it harder to live on their own. Yet not every student has the support of parents to fall back on, or enough money to even share the rent with a few other roommates.

College students are a notoriously thrifty bunch, living on a diet of Top Ramen and powering their cars with crossed fingers and whatever change hides in their pockets, yet a lack of disposable income does not necessarily qualify you for low-income housing.

"The system was not designed, or intended, for (a majority of) college students," said Jerry Brevier, a Housing Management Coordinator for the Low Income and Affordable Housing Institute.

"This is a program for the homeless and soon to be homeless, senior citizens and the disabled, and people who do not make enough money or have the ability to pay rent and [support families]."

Still, there are a number of students who can and will benefit greatly from low income housing. It is important, however, to know both your rights and your landlords, and to be aware of the regulations involved so you don't suddenly end up on the street or be found ineligible and owe back rent to the government.

Low Income housing is defined by the government as housing that costs its residents 30 percent or less of their total annual income, and is only available to those who make less than 60 percent of the annual median income of the area in which they live. In Snohomish County, the most recent figures on the median income set it at $54,584, which means you must make less than 32,750$ to qualify. College students cannot legally apply if they are taking or plan to take more than 12 credits a semester.

Most people who live in Low Income Housing are also able to get some, most, or all of their rent paid for by the government under Section 8 of the US Housing Act of 1937. In 2006, however, numerous regulations were introduced after loopholes in the law allowed college students to not count money they received towards their college education as part of their total income.

Aid under Section 8 is now only available for college students who meet one of the following criteria:

Over 24.
Veterans of the Military.
Married, but still meeting income limitations.
Parents of a child considered a dependent for tax purposes.
Children of parents who both could qualify for low-income housing.


These, it should be noted, are the most basic rules - the housing authority in the county in which you live, or the landlord you are renting from may have their own rules. The Snohomish County Housing Authority did not return calls for a statement.

"We hear from people, time to time, who take advantage of this program," said Brevier. "It really is sad to me, because {Low Income Housing} is like welfare; it's for those that need it."

WSU Student and internet blogger 'Kirt' recently wrote about his interaction with his landlord after he was found to be in noncompliance. He talked via email with the author about some of the problems that come about when either the landlord or the tenant break the agreements.

"I lived in a low income housing complex for a few months and started taking more than the 12 credits [allowed, but I didn't report it.] The [landlord somehow found out], and threatened to [turn me into the government] unless I paid him [much higher rent]." 'Kirt' did not say how the situation turned out, or provide details to confirm his story.

"There are real legal consequences to lying about this sort of thing," said Brevier. "You can be charged with fraud and [many other charges, depending on your case.]"

According to a police report put out by the Department of Justice in 2007, lying to receive Low Income Housing is "a felony that provides for a term of imprisonment of up to five years and a fine of up to $250,000 upon conviction."

Our area offers a lot of opportunities to take advantage of this program, and though as college students it is much harder to qualify, for those that need it low income housing could be a lifeline.

Link to article

Wednesday, May 6, 2009

The decline and fall of affordable housing

The downtown that Portland builds should open doors for people of all income levels
Sunday, March 04, 2007 By MARTHA GIES
The Oregonian


Jerome Henwood still smolders over a rent hike that sent him packing. "It's not just the homeless who are hurting," he insists. "It's the low-income elderly and disabled, and we're being pushed out of downtown." Henwood, 62, moved into an 11-story market-rate apartment building on Southwest Park Avenue in 2002. The rent was $670, but he made do with just Social Security. "It had a rooftop garden," he says, and he loved the location, just south of Portland State University. Then a California equity group bought the building, and just 15 days before his lease was to expire, he learned his rent would jump to $1,055, just $2 shy of his monthly income. And he's not the only one who's been forced out of downtown.

During the last decade, downtown Portland has become a privileged place to live, as condominiums sprouted from the Pearl District to South Waterfront and rental buildings in between have been flipped into condos. Longtime residents -- minimum wage-earners or retirees on fixed incomes such as Henwood -- watched their rents soar and affordable units disappear.
Unless we're willing to write off downtown as an enclave for the well-to-do -- or for the few addicts lucky enough to get treatment and housing -- we must muster the political will to build more truly affordable rentals. The city manages deals all the time. Just look at the $57 million aerial tram, the $45 million upgrade of Civic Stadium and the $42 million snazzy little streetcar.

Portland's vaunted livability attracts people with money. But let's not end up like San Francisco, where dot-com money took over the city, driving the middle class to the suburbs and the poor to the streets. Four pertinent new reports give us a snapshot of where Portland stands now. It's a mixed picture. The Portland Development Commission just finalized its recommendations for spending the new tax increment set-aside from urban renewal districts that the City Council earmarked for affordable housing: $162.6 million over the next six years. This time around, PDC increased its commitment to build as many as 1,450 units specifically for people who pay no more than 30 percent of their income for rent. That's citywide, too, not just downtown. The U. S. Department of Housing and Urban Development will release new median income figures any day now. This could trigger rent increases in income-restricted buildings, since landlords are allowed to raise rents whenever the medium income rises.

Northwest Pilot Project's Downtown Portland Affordable Housing Inventory -- expected to be about 3,400 units -- will be published after new rents are announced. Here, the affordable ceiling is set just $35 higher than what a single person working full time at Oregon's minimum wage can pay -- $425 per month.
Figures for the first two years of the city's Ten-Year Plan to End Homelessness indicate it's working, with fewer people living on the street. But it has created even more competition for the dwindling low-income rental stock because, thus far, no new units have been added.

Wrong direction

Portland turned onto the path of high prices and tight supply when, in a move to clean up things, the city tore down a lot of low-income housing in the '70s. As late as 1974, an estimated 6,000 units still existed downtown; but a 1978 report showed 738 units lost since 1970 in the Lownsdale and Yamhill districts alone. It looked as if subsidized housing could make up for the lower-end rental housing lost when landlords signed the first 20-year HUD contracts in 1977. In subsidized buildings in which tenants pay 30 percent of their income for rent, and the government makes up the difference. Subsidies help keep buildings rented at market rate and also help the renter -- just as government-guaranteed loans and income tax deductions help those of us paying mortgages.

But with the Reagan budget cuts to HUD programs in the '80s, homelessness exploded nationally. In Portland, it took until 1988 to get a grip on the loss, and the City Council passed a resolution: the 5,183 low-income downtown housing units that existed in April 1978 would be maintained. We've never pulled that off.

Ten years ago, HUD contracts signed in the '70s began to expire. At the Roosevelt Plaza on Southwest Park, 58 people received eviction notices in 1997. Northwest Pilot Project, which had helped seniors displaced from downtown hotels for decades, and director Susan Emmons negotiated a postponement. For the first time, owners helped pay some relocation costs. As the person Northwest Pilot Project sent to help tenants find new homes, I was the unwitting agent of the destruction of a community, a family really. Many of these people were long-term tenants -- among them people in wheelchairs, or suffering schizophrenia, or speaking only Korean -- and they loved their home, right on the Park Blocks and convenient to Safeway. After those people moved, the building went condo.

If the Roosevelt evictions were my personal introduction to the brutal side of gentrification, they also were a turning point in public awareness of the problem. The Oregonian ran four major articles on the loss, including a front-page photo of tiny Olive Lacsamana, 93, sitting alone in her tidy room before eviction.

So in 1998, when the Oak's contract expired, the city bought the building to maintain 90 apartments as subsidized housing, and they remain so today. The city passed a preservation ordinance the same year. It requires any owner opting out of a HUD contract to first offer to sell the building to the city, so low rents can be preserved. Unfortunately, the ordinance has not been enforced, and when the Western Rooms quietly converted to market-rate rentals in 2001, we lost 39 units of subsidized housing. Which is not to say that all landlords are ready to bolt. The largest HUD contract downtown, Clay Tower with 235 subsidized one-bedroom units, expires this December, and the Schnitzer family, which owns the building, is trying to negotiate a meaningful extension from a cash-stripped HUD.
These HUD buildings are a critical part of the housing picture, and the new inventory will show 1,040 HUD units downtown.
Less successful have been the income-restricted buildings, first built here in the '90s in exchange for tax credits. The income restrictions are too high. A one-bedroom "60 percent" apartment rents for $709 a month, while the elderly that Northwest Pilot Project serve typically average $750 in monthly incomes. The new inventory of affordable housing downtown will also show the trend away from open-market housing for the general low-income public, toward housing targeting special needs: corrections clients, the chronically homeless and people in recovery.

One reason for this shift is the Ten-Year Plan to End Homelessness. It addresses only the chronically homeless, defined as single, disabled people who have been homeless for a year or more, or homeless multiple times. Defenders of this plan argue that the chronically homeless cost millions by burdening courts, jails, hospitals and sanitation systems.
The Ten-Year Plan report claims 480 new housing units. Yet, except for the 60 units at 8 N.W. 8th Ave., on the drawing board as early as 1999, nothing has been built downtown. All the others are existing low-income housing and were simply co-opted by the plan from the existing pool of low-income affordable housing stock. Let's not set up a system under which someone has to be chronically homeless before being able to get a place to live.
So now what are our options?

At the federal level, we are just going to hope to outlive the current administration's cuts to vital HUD housing programs.
At the state level, we need to reverse the proscription against a real-estate transfer tax so that we can enact one here and use money to finance new low-income housing. More immediately, Senate Bill 38 could generate approximately $60 million per biennium for housing by increasing the document recording fee from $21 to $36, with the additional revenue going to Oregon Housing and Community Services. The fee is charged for paperwork processing when a property changes hands.
And locally, we have the new tax-increment financing revenues, though they are not going to bring us to our goal downtown. Also, as we do create units, some of which will be in the South Park Blocks and Downtown Waterfront Urban Renewal Areas, lets not earmark all of them for the chronically homeless, leaving the elderly and the working poor out of the mix.
This is a real estate problem, and we need to solve it at a real estate level. For myself, I'm still haunted by Olive Lacsamana at the Roosevelt and all the other low-income elderly that we continue to shuffle around this city.
In the meantime -- though you can't see it from the top of the tram -- downtown Portland is 1,800 affordable housing units short of our 5,183-unit downtown goal.

Martha Gies is the author of "Up All Night" and many short stories and essays published over the last 30 years. A longtime low-income housing activist, she has helped relocate tenants from the Roosevelt Plaza, Clifford Hotel, Western Rooms, St. Francis Hotel and the Ace Apartments. Since 1996, she has done the housing counts for the Downtown Portland Affordable Housing Inventory.

Link to article

Monday, May 4, 2009

Efforts to Restrict Sprawl Find New Resistance From Advocates for Affordable Housin

By RICHARD A. OPPEL Jr.
Published: Tuesday, December 26, 2000


Until this year, Habitat for Humanity affiliates in Arizona and Colorado never felt a need to get involved in a political fight. But in the fall they jumped into a battle against a seemingly unlikely foe: the environmental movement.

In one of the most far-reaching efforts yet to curb suburban sprawl, ballot initiatives in both states proposed giving voters an unprecedented level of power to designate wide swaths of land off limits to new housing.

Officials with Habitat, which builds low-income housing for needy families, feared that the measures would drive up the cost of land and ''basically shut down our ability to acquire land and lots for growth,'' said Chris Wolf, the organization's director in Phoenix. So the Habitat affiliates joined with developers to oppose the initiatives; in Colorado, opponents even made a television commercial highlighting Habitat's objections.

Nobody argues in favor of suburban congestion. But increasingly the debate over sprawl has turned to whether laws intended to fight it are playing a role in driving up housing prices, at a time when housing affordability in many parts of the country has dipped to its lowest level in almost a decade.

The success of anti-sprawl efforts is evident in the increasing number of communities that have adopted measures like low-density zoning, moratoriums on building permits or voter-approved growth boundaries. Although the Arizona and Colorado initiatives were defeated last month, many similar local proposals in California passed, and battles over anti-sprawl laws continue to rage in suburbs outside Washington, Atlanta, Dallas and other big cities.

Although the battles have been concentrated in the rapidly growing South and West, sprawl has been a concern in the densely populated Northeast as well. Only two years ago voters in New Jersey approved borrowing $1 billion to help preserve about a million acres of farmland and woodland.

As anti-sprawl measures proliferate, developers have enlisted affordable-housing advocates to promote the view that the restrictions make higher home prices inevitable, in effect amounting to a tax on prospective home buyers that hits the working and middle classes hardest.

''One of the unintentional byproducts of efforts to control sprawl is to restrict the amount of land available for housing,'' said Nicolas P. Retsinas, a former Clinton administration housing official who is director of the Joint Center for Housing Studies, at Harvard University. ''When you restrict supply in the face of increased demand, what a surprise! Prices go up.''

Efforts to limit construction, critics say, can affect all types of housing, from apartments to mansions. Builders and other opponents contend that even when the limits mainly affect more expensive homes, the trickle-down consequences include rising prices for more modest housing.

But environmentalists and other supporters of growth controls say there is little proof that such measures have any significant impact on housing prices. Susan LeFever, director of the Rocky Mountain chapter of the Sierra Club, notes that cities without strong growth-control laws have seen huge run-ups in home prices, a result of the nation's economic boom.

''It's certainly easy to pull out examples of places with growth restrictions where the cost of housing has gone up,'' she said. ''But it's equally easy to pull out places that don't have growth restrictions where the cost of housing has gone up just as much.''

Unless there is a recession severe enough to slow suburban development, experts expect anti-sprawl measures to remain popular with voters and local elected officials.

California saw more growth-related proposals on local ballots this year than at any other time since 1990, before the state plunged into recession, said Bill Fulton, president of the Solimar Research Group, public policy analysts in Ventura, Calif. During the last four years, he said, there have been 118 slow-growth initiatives in California, nearly twice as many as in the prior four-year period.

Most of the proposals in California this year were approved, although a few larger ones failed, notably in San Francisco and Sonoma County.

''In an economic boom is when you see growth restrictions come back,'' Mr. Fulton said, ''but they tend to lag behind a few years.''

In King County, Wash. -- Seattle and environs -- housing costs have soared so high that county officials recently ordered a study of whether the state's rules restricting development outside cities was helping drive up prices.

The ''surprising conclusion'' of the report, due out next month, is that there is no proof the rules have more than a negligible effect on home prices, said Ron Sims, the county executive. He attributes the jump in housing costs to the region's tremendous prosperity and rising incomes, noting that the housing market flattened out this year after the Nasdaq swooned.

In Cary, N.C., though, an affluent town of nearly 100,000 outside Raleigh, Mayor Glen Lang says home prices are already being affected by slow-growth measures approved in the last few years.

''When you have demand and decrease supply, prices rise dramatically,'' Mr. Lang said.

Both sides of the debate point to the same example: Portland, Ore.

Development is limited outside the growth boundary that has ringed Portland since the 1970's, and critics contend that this is why the city has seen home prices skyrocket. According to the government's Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight, average home prices in the Portland-Vancouver, Wash., metropolitan area have risen 148 percent in the last dozen years.

''The development controls have acted as a long-run drag on housing supplies,'' said Gerard Mildner, an associate professor of urban studies and planning at Portland State University. ''The desire to protect open space and farmland has trumped people's concerns about housing affordability.''

Defenders of the Portland boundary, however, note that cities without similar growth controls have also seen steep price increases over the same period, including a 128 percent rise in Denver and a 116 percent rise in Salt Lake City-Ogden, Utah.

A study published this summer in the journal Contemporary Economic Policy concluded that while the Portland growth boundary ''has likely imposed upward pressure on prices, the results indicate that the effect has been fairly modest,'' most likely less than $10,000 for a typical home. Higher land prices have been offset by a trend toward smaller lots and other elements of higher-density housing, said one of the study's authors, Eban Goodstein, an economics professor at Lewis and Clark College in Portland.

The debate over growth controls is made all the more intense because of the unequal way the nation's long economic boom has treated Americans. While the last decade has created tremendous wealth, many people -- teachers, police officers, nurses and many others in middle-class jobs -- have watched the cost of housing rise faster than their incomes.

The median price for a single-family home rose about 45 percent during the 1990's, according to the National Association of Realtors. For the wealthiest fifth of American families, that was no problem, as their mean incomes rose 57 percent during that time, according to the Census Bureau.

But the incomes of most other families failed to keep pace with housing prices. The least affluent two-fifths of American families, for example, saw their incomes grow just 35 percent.

While the hottest housing markets have cooled recently -- prices fell slightly in the San Francisco Bay Area, Seattle and Portland during the third quarter, according to the National Association of Realtors -- there has been no letup in much of the rest of the country. Prices rose 5 percent in the Midwest and 4 percent in the South during the quarter.

In the last decade, the rise in home prices has been offset somewhat by lower mortgage rates. But during the third quarter, housing affordability reached its worst level since 1992. (Affordability should improve in the fourth quarter, as rates have dropped a good bit since the summer.) Some experts are concerned that the drop in affordability will slow recent gains in the percentage of American families who own their own homes -- advances that have resulted partly from loans made on such less-restrictive terms as smaller down payments.

And concerns about affordability extend to renters: a study issued this year by the Department of Housing and Urban Development found that 5.4 million renter families either spent more than half their income on rent or lived in ''severely inadequate'' housing in 1997.

In Congress, developers have used the affordability issue to seek relief from restrictions on construction. But while builders argue that excessive growth controls can hurt the local economy, some local elected officials say there is also an economic danger in not doing enough to preserve natural amenities.

''If you're going to manage growth, you can't kill the goose that laid the golden egg,'' said Kirk Watson, the mayor here in Austin, where home prices have soared during the technology boom. Much of the credit for Austin's boom belongs to the city's beautiful rolling hills and other natural features, which have helped attract a talented labor force, the mayor said.

''The new economic paradigm is about the knowledge economy, and that is always going to follow the quality of life,'' Mr. Watson said. ''Part of managing this boom and growth is preserving what the knowledge economy was looking for in the first place.''

Photos: A recently completed housing development in growing Phoenix nearly encroaches on a park. (Associated Press); Chris Wolf of Habitat for Humanity says an Arizona ballot initiative would have crippled the Phoenix affiliate. (Jeff Topping for The New York Times) Chart: ''STATUS REPORT: Elusive Dream'' For all but the wealthiest families, income did not keep up with the rising cost of a home during the 1990's. All changes: 1990 through 1999. Chart shows cost of homes for poorest and wealthiest familes since 1990. (Sources: Census Bureau; National Association of Realtors)

Link to article

Saturday, May 2, 2009

What is mixed-income housing?


To address questions raised by regionwide households exploring housing options within the new mixed-income communities under development in Chicago, MPC worked with a variety of stakeholders to publish the attached brochure answering the question "What is mixed-income housing?" .

Chicago’s new mixed-income developments are being built as a part of a broader transformation effort of key City neighborhoods. Some sites are already complete and others are just opening or will begin construction soon.

These communities include homes at market-rate prices, along with affordable opportunities for rent (targeting families making up to 60% of AMI or approximately $45,000 per year for a household of four) and for sale (for families making up to 120% of AMI or around $90,000 per year). There are also homes reserved for qualifying public housing residents.

Click here for the brochure

Thursday, April 30, 2009

Social Equity, Gentrification and New Urbanism

First, a review of some generally accepted criteria that identify a development as New Urbanism, or, as we prefer to call it, Traditional Neighborhood Development.

From a market and development perspective, the neighborhood is the building block of community, in the same way that the block is the building block of a neighborhood.

A Traditional Neighborhood theoretically encompasses 125 acres to accommodate a five-minute walk to the neighborhood center.
A Traditional Neighborhood includes a variety of residential units, from inexpensive rentals to high-priced detached houses.
A Traditional Neighborhood has a continuous street network with a hierarchy of streets, from high-capacity boulevards to narrow rear lanes or alleys. Neighborhood streets should have relatively narrow cartways, small curb radii, and sidewalks, to accommodate pedestrians and bicyclists as well as motor vehicles..
A Traditional Neighborhood has streets fronted by private or public uses;. Parking lots and garage doors should not face the street. Front doors should.
A Traditional Neighborhood has a Neighborhood Center, which is organized around a civic place, such as a plaza or green, and includes higher-density residential as well as, potentially, a mix of non-residential uses.
If the area is large enough to accommodate more than one neighborhood, a Traditional Neighborhood can even have a Town Center, serving several neighborhoods–with a mix of civic, commercial, retail and residential uses.
There are a number of other criteria that are used by planning firms, but for us, as market analysts, these are the most important criteria from both the market and the development perspectives.

First, the issue of gentrification, particularly considering the track record of most New Urbanist developments to rapidly escalate in value.

In 1998, before dot-com and high-tech companies drove California real estate through the roof, the three least affordable cities in the United States were New York, San Francisco and El Paso, Texas. El Paso was number three, not because its real estate values were so high–they’re not. There are actually new single-family detached houses for sale in El Paso for about $65,000. El Paso was number three because its per capita incomes were so very low, that even with an average sales prices of less than $80,000, only a small percentage of households could qualify to buy a new house.

New York and San Francisco have serious problems with displacement of existing residents caused by gentrification. El Paso does not. Values are so high in New York and San Francisco that low-income neighborhoods are rapidly being gentrified and the existing residents are rapidly being forced out.

The City of Wheeling, West Virginia has so many vacant housing units in and near the downtown that the city is desperate to have affluent households move in and upgrade the housing stock. In Wheeling, displacement is not even an issue.

Gentrification in and of itself is not a malign social development; displacement of existing poor residents as a result of neighborhood gentrification is.

Although one of the principal values of New Urbanism is to provide new housing for all kinds of people, with a wide range of incomes, the reality is that, for the most part, New Urbanist communities provide new housing for middle-to upper-income households.

Why? One of the principal reasons is that there are a variety of impediments–from high land costs, lengthy approvals process, difficulties in obtaining financing–to bringing a new development to market that tend to inflate values beyond the reach of the low end of the market. It is difficult to provide affordable housing, and stay in business, when a builder is facing development costs of more than $75 a square foot. The grim reality of new development, or redevelopment, is that it is nearly impossible to provide "affordable" housing without some form of significant public (meaning government) participation, through a variety of mechanisms, including rent subsidies to low-income renters; grants and low-interest loans to low-income buyers; density bonuses, tax credits, TIFs, and property tax abatements, among other programs, to builders and developers.

A number of states, counties and cities have addressed the issue of affordable housing through what is known as inclusionary zoning policies. These policies take a number of different approaches, but two of the most "successful" in terms of actually getting substantial numbers of affordable housing units built, are in Montgomery County, Maryland and the State of New Jersey.

Montgomery County requires that at least 12 to 15 percent of the dwelling units proposed for a new development of 50 or more units be affordable, which is defined as 60 percent of the area median income.

The State of New Jersey requires that each municipality provides its "fair share" of affordable housing, as determined by COAH, or the Council on Affordable Housing. The individual municipality can achieve its fair share in a variety of ways:

By loans to residents to create accessory apartments that are affordable to low-income households;
By developing and building the required number of units;
By paying "X" amount of dollars per unit, as determined by COAH, to another New Jersey municipality that has a high proportion of residents living in substandard dwelling units; and
By providing those units within new development projects, through density bonuses to the developer.
These are laudable programs. However, the implementation of these policies are a perfect example of the law of unintended consequences.

Here is a townhouse development in Clinton, New Jersey.

Compare the market-rate units with the affordable housing units, which positively shout "affordable, affordable."

How can New Urbanist planning and design techniques have an impact on social equity, or the provision of housing for people with a wide range of incomes, household composition, and lifestyles, and how does it differ from conventional approaches to affordable housing?

The key is the ability of New Urbanist planning and design to provide for a wide variety of housing types within the same development, the same neighborhood, and even the same block.

Example: Wyndcrest, 26-unit Duany Plater-Zyberk designed landplan.

On a larger scale, HUD’s adoption of New Urbanist planning techniques for the revitalization and redevelopment of failed public housing, through its HOPE VI program, provides some of the best and most successful examples of how New Urbanism achieves the integration of not only incomes–the mix of public replacement housing, tax credit, and market-rate–but housing types–including rental and for-sale apartments, townhouses and duplexes, and a wide range of single-family detached houses.

Urban example is the First Ward, in Charlotte, North Carolina, planned by Urban Design Associates.

In addition to public housing rentals, and family self-sufficiency units, the First Ward contains market-rate rentals, and for-sale units, ranging from condominiums priced under $150,000, townhouses priced between $150,000 and $200,000, and single-family detached houses priced up to $300,000.

Suburban example is Park du Valle, in Louisville, Kentucky, also planned by Urban Design Associates, which, from a market perspective, is one of the most successful and fully realized Hope VI redevelopments.

All of the rental units, both market-rate and public housing, are fully leased, and the developer has a waiting list of more than 4,000 applications.

Prices for the single-family houses range from $75,000 and $240,000, a price range comparable to conventional subdivisions in Louisville. The houses on Algonquin Parkway (a boulevard designed by Frederick Law Olmsted) ranged in price from $150,000 to $400,000.

What makes a New Urbanist-designed neighborhood work?

by Laurie Volk, 2001

The neighborhood must have the appropriate balance. Too many low-income units, particularly in the first phase, and the neighborhood runs the risk of retaining the stigma of a "project." Too many market-rate units and the neighborhood runs the risk of being accused of gentrification at the expense of residents who already live there.

Successful implementation rests on several critical development principles that are common to the establishment of all healthy neighborhoods, and are intrinsic to New Urbanism:

Buildings must be designed to enhance the public realm, facing well-defined, walkable streets, to provide the "eyes on the street" that will ensure public safety.
To achieve the goal of a truly mixed-income, mixed-tenure neighborhood, the rental and for-sale units should be interspersed throughout the community, rather than located in single-use "pods."
Logical relationships between densities and tenures must be established, from both the market perspective and the property management perspective. In the case of Park duValle in Louisville, Kentucky, this was achieved through a progression of density on a given street, moving from a six-unit apartment building on the corner to a rental duplex or triplex building to for-sale single-family detached houses in mid-block.
The occupants’ income level or tenure must not be discernible from the street. All units should have the same quality of materials and design, inside and out.
A neighborhood that has enduring value must be a place of rich diversity, not only of incomes and housing tenures, but also of options and opportunities for all residents.

Link to article